Tuesday, 25 November 2014 / TRUTH-OUT.ORG

Taking a Closer Look at Inequality

Thursday, 27 March 2014 10:19 By Paul Krugman, Krugman & Co. | Op-Ed

Workers checking molten steel at one of the blast furnaces of the Arcelormittal steel mill in Dunkerque, France, earlier this year. (Photo: Andrew Testa for The New York Times)Workers checking molten steel at one of the blast furnaces of the Arcelormittal steel mill in Dunkerque, France, earlier this year. (Photo: Andrew Testa for The New York Times)

I promised recently that I would share some nagging concerns about a paper on redistribution and growth by Jonathan D. Ostry, Andrew Berg and Charalambos G. Tsangarides, researchers at the International Monetary Fund. They conclude that there is no negative effect of redistributionist policies, at least within the range we normally see, and quite possibly a positive effect from the reduction in inequality.

I think I can usefully phrase my concerns in terms of my favorite comparison on these matters, which is between the United States and France.

Why this pair? Because we're talking about two advanced countries that clearly have similar levels of technological competence but have made very different social policy choices. In particular, France not only does much more redistribution, but has expanded its redistribution over time, limiting the rise in overall inequality, while the United States has not.

So how have the countries' destinies compared during the New Gilded Age? Growth actually has been somewhat slower in France, although it's hardly the catastrophe that the incessant bad press about the country might lead you to expect (see the chart on real gross domestic product per capita on this page.)

2014.3.25.Krugman.Chart.GDP

Even more strikingly, however, the level, as opposed to the growth rate, of French G.D.P. per capita is substantially lower than that of the United States.

This is my main concern about Ostry et al. Suppose a person thinks that strong redistributionist policies reduce the level of output - but that it's a one-time shift, not a permanent depression of growth. Then he could accept their result of a lack of impact on growth while still believing in serious output effects.

Now, the I.M.F. researchers arguably have answered this objection by also including the current level of G.D.P. per capita in their regressions, which indicate that a country with lower G.D.P. per capita than the United States should be growing faster than the United States, other things being equal. So any level-depressing effect of redistribution should show up as a failure of this faster growth to materialize. But I'm uneasy about whether this is good enough.

Interestingly, French underperformance is a matter of low labor input rather than low productivity (see the second chart).

2014.3.25.Krugman.Chart.Productivity

Once you delve into this low labor input, it starts to look like the result of some very specific policies rather than redistribution in general: a pension system that encourages early retirement, regulations that give French people shorter hours and much more vacation time than we get.

Overall, I am still mostly persuaded by the I.M.F. paper, but I think we need to acknowledge that it's not quite as slam-dunky as liberals might like.

© 2014 The New York Times Company
Truthout has licensed this content. It may not be reproduced by any other source and is not covered by our Creative Commons license.
Paul Krugman joined The New York Times in 1999 as a columnist on the Op-Ed page and continues as a professor of economics and international affairs at Princeton University. He was awarded the Nobel in economic science in 2008. Mr Krugman is the author or editor of 20 books and more than 200 papers in professional journals and edited volumes, including "The Return of Depression Economics" (2008) and "The Conscience of a Liberal" (2007).
Copyright 2014 The New York Times.

Hide Comments

blog comments powered by Disqus
GET DAILY TRUTHOUT UPDATES

FOLLOW togtorsstottofb


Latest Stories

Taking a Closer Look at Inequality

Thursday, 27 March 2014 10:19 By Paul Krugman, Krugman & Co. | Op-Ed

Workers checking molten steel at one of the blast furnaces of the Arcelormittal steel mill in Dunkerque, France, earlier this year. (Photo: Andrew Testa for The New York Times)Workers checking molten steel at one of the blast furnaces of the Arcelormittal steel mill in Dunkerque, France, earlier this year. (Photo: Andrew Testa for The New York Times)

I promised recently that I would share some nagging concerns about a paper on redistribution and growth by Jonathan D. Ostry, Andrew Berg and Charalambos G. Tsangarides, researchers at the International Monetary Fund. They conclude that there is no negative effect of redistributionist policies, at least within the range we normally see, and quite possibly a positive effect from the reduction in inequality.

I think I can usefully phrase my concerns in terms of my favorite comparison on these matters, which is between the United States and France.

Why this pair? Because we're talking about two advanced countries that clearly have similar levels of technological competence but have made very different social policy choices. In particular, France not only does much more redistribution, but has expanded its redistribution over time, limiting the rise in overall inequality, while the United States has not.

So how have the countries' destinies compared during the New Gilded Age? Growth actually has been somewhat slower in France, although it's hardly the catastrophe that the incessant bad press about the country might lead you to expect (see the chart on real gross domestic product per capita on this page.)

2014.3.25.Krugman.Chart.GDP

Even more strikingly, however, the level, as opposed to the growth rate, of French G.D.P. per capita is substantially lower than that of the United States.

This is my main concern about Ostry et al. Suppose a person thinks that strong redistributionist policies reduce the level of output - but that it's a one-time shift, not a permanent depression of growth. Then he could accept their result of a lack of impact on growth while still believing in serious output effects.

Now, the I.M.F. researchers arguably have answered this objection by also including the current level of G.D.P. per capita in their regressions, which indicate that a country with lower G.D.P. per capita than the United States should be growing faster than the United States, other things being equal. So any level-depressing effect of redistribution should show up as a failure of this faster growth to materialize. But I'm uneasy about whether this is good enough.

Interestingly, French underperformance is a matter of low labor input rather than low productivity (see the second chart).

2014.3.25.Krugman.Chart.Productivity

Once you delve into this low labor input, it starts to look like the result of some very specific policies rather than redistribution in general: a pension system that encourages early retirement, regulations that give French people shorter hours and much more vacation time than we get.

Overall, I am still mostly persuaded by the I.M.F. paper, but I think we need to acknowledge that it's not quite as slam-dunky as liberals might like.

© 2014 The New York Times Company
Truthout has licensed this content. It may not be reproduced by any other source and is not covered by our Creative Commons license.
Paul Krugman joined The New York Times in 1999 as a columnist on the Op-Ed page and continues as a professor of economics and international affairs at Princeton University. He was awarded the Nobel in economic science in 2008. Mr Krugman is the author or editor of 20 books and more than 200 papers in professional journals and edited volumes, including "The Return of Depression Economics" (2008) and "The Conscience of a Liberal" (2007).
Copyright 2014 The New York Times.

Hide Comments

blog comments powered by Disqus